برآورد میزان تاثیر توهم پولی برتابع مطلوبیت خانوارهای ایرانی: رهیافت معادلات اولر و روش GMM

نوع مقاله : مقاله پژوهشی

نویسنده

دانشیارگروه اقتصاد، دانشکده کسب و کار و اقتصاد، دانشگاه خلیج فارس، بوشهر، ایران

چکیده

در این مقاله با ورود تورم در تابع ترجیحات خانوارها در قالب مدل قیمت گذاری دارایی مصرف (CCAPM)، اقدام به برآورد میزان تاثیرگذاری توهم پولی بر مطلوبیت خانوارهای ایرانی در دوره 1400-1357 شده است. در واقع، به طور درونزا، تورم وارد کرنل قیمت‌گذاری تابع مطلوبیتی شده که هم به مصرف واقعی و هم به مصرف اسمی بستگی دارد که تابعی مناسب برای کارگزار با توهم جزیی پول می‌باشد. از این رو، از تابع ترجیحات بازگشتی ارایه شده توسط اپستین- زین و از یک تابع مطلوبیت توانی غیر بازگشتی با ریسک‌گریزی نسبی ثابت به گونه ای استفاده شده که متغیر رشد تورم به عنوان یک عامل ریسکی در عامل تنزیل تصادفی معادلات اولرِ استخراجی ظاهر گردد. سپس، از روش گشتاورهای تعمیم یافته و معیارهای MAE و MSE برای تخمین سیستم‌‌های معادلات و انتخاب مناسب ترین مدل استفاده شد. معیارهای مذکور، برتر بودن ترجیحات بازگشتی را تایید می کنند. نتایج پژوهش، بیانگر آن است که پارامتر توهم پولی از نظر آماری معنا دار بوده و آماره J هانسن نیز مناسب بودن ابزارها را تایید می‌کند. در مدل برتر، تاثیر توهم پولی بر مطلوبیت خانوارها 18 درصد می باشد. بنابراین با توجه به میزان تاثیرگذاری توهم پولی بر تابع مطلوبیت که نسبتا قابل ملاحظه است، لازمست برنامه ریزان و سیاستگذاران اقتصادی در جهت کنترل تورم و به تبعِ آن کاهش تاثیر گذاری توهم پولی بر مطلوبیت خانوارها اهتمام ورزند. همچنین ، بر ورود متغیر تورم به عنوان عامل ریسکی در توابع مطلوبیت استفاده شده در مدل های قیمت‌گذاری دارایی ها تاکید می گردد

کلیدواژه‌ها

موضوعات


عنوان مقاله [English]

Estimating the effect of money illusion on the utility function of Iranian households: with Euler equations and GMM approach

نویسنده [English]

  • Reza Roshan
Associate Professor of Economics, Faculty of Business and Economics, Persian Gulf University, Bushehr, Iran.
چکیده [English]

Purpose: Extensive evidence shows that consumption-based asset pricing models (CCAPM) proposed by Lucas (1978) and Breeden (1979) have failed to explain average stock returns in cross-sectional data. In this context, we can refer to the studies of Breeden, Gibbons and Litzenberg (1989), Letas and Ludwigson (2001), and Jacobs and Wong (2004). In response to this failure, several studies used other variables than consumption growth in a single-factor model to improve the performance of the mentioned structure (such as Parker and Julliard (2005), Jaganthan and Wong (2007), Savo (2011) and Kroenke (2017)). In none of the domestic studies, inflation has been used as a risk factor. Therefore, this study aims to fill this gap by focusing on the impact of monetary illusion on the desirability of Iranian households in the period under review. In fact, this research is of novelty compared to the previous studies conducted inside the country. Firstly, with the inclusion of the inflation variable in the household preferences function, the CCAPM model has been developed in such a way that the inflation variable can be included in the household preferences function. Secondly, reversible preferences and non-reversible power utility have been used to estimate the monetary illusion parameter. Thirdly, in this research, the system of equations includes the return of various assets such as bank interest rate, stock return, housing return and labor wage return, and the parameters of the equations have been estimated by using different appropriate tools. 
Methodology: In order to include inflation as a risk factor and define a parameter that shows the degree of monetary illusion of brokers, Mayo (2018) specified a three-factor macro model for asset pricing including inflation rate, consumption growth and asset yield in the CCAPM structure. The underlying framework of the model includes a recursive inter-period utility presented by Epstein-Zine and Weil (1989). This framework made use of an intra-period utility function that corresponds to both real consumption growth and nominal consumption growth (with the specification a Cobb-Douglas function). Intra-period utility is appropriate for a case where the investor faces a partial monetary illusion, which is because he cannot fully distinguish real consumption from nominal consumption in his consumption/asset allocation decision. The degree of monetary illusion is represented by the monetary illusion parameter (ϵ), which varies from zero to one. Therefore, the assumption of monetary illusion allows the researcher to create a model in which the inflation variable is used as an endogenous risk factor in the pricing kernel. In this regard, there are three preferences parameters in the created model, including relative risk aversion coefficient, monetary illusion parameter, and inter-period substitution elasticity.
In this study, inflation is included in the function of households' preferences in the form of consumption capital asset pricing model (CCAPM) so as to estimate the impact of money illusion on the utility of Iranian households in the period of 1978-2021 To this end, the recursive preferences function provided by Epstein-Zin and a non-recursive power utility function with constant relative risk aversion are used in such a way that the inflation growth variable appears as a risk factor in the stochastic discount factor of the derived Euler equations. In fact, inflation arises endogenously in the pricing kernel by assuming an intra-temporal utility that depends on both real and nominal consumption. This suits an investor with partial money illusion. Then, the generalized moments method (GMM), MAE and MSE criteria are used to estimate the systems of equations and select the most appropriate model.
Findings and discussion: After the mentioned models are estimated, the mean absolute magnitude of errors (MAE) and mean squared errors (MSE) criteria are used to select the best model among the fitted ones. The results show that the model with recursive preferences has the lowest values ​​for the two mentioned statistics. Therefore, this model is chosen as the best one, based on which the effect of monetary illusion on the utility function of Iranian households has been 18% during the period under review. The criteria prove the superiority of recursive preferences. The results of the research also indicate that the money illusion parameter is statistically significant, and Hansen's J statistics confirm the appropriateness of the instruments. In the superior model, the effect of money illusion on the desirability of households is 0.18. The significance of the coefficients and the fit statistics of the models show that the inclusion of the data related to inflation growth in capital asset pricing models as a risk factor alongside the risk factor of consumption growth and asset return portfolio is significant.
Conclusions and policy implications: The findings show that, in the first model where return preferences are used, the effect of monetary illusion on consumers' desirability is 0.18. Also, in the second model, which is bounded by the first model and involves non-reversibility and ability utility, the effect of monetary illusion on the utility of Iranian households is 0.03. In both estimates, all the coefficients are statistically significant, and the diagnostic tests for the remaining phrases confirm the correctness of the estimates. After the models are estimated, the mean absolute magnitude of errors (MAE) and the mean squared errors (MSE) criteria are used to select the best model among the fitted ones. The results show that the model with recursive preferences has the lowest values in the two types of statistics. Therefore, this model is chosen as the best one. Based on it, the effect of monetary illusion on the utility function of Iranian households is found to have been 18% during the period under review. Considering the relative impact of monetary illusion on the utility of households, it is necessary for policy makers and planners to reduce and control prices in order to better adapt the utility of households to economic realities.

کلیدواژه‌ها [English]

  • consumption-based capital asset pricing models
  • inflation risk
  • money illusion
  • Euler equations
  • GMM
Adegboye, Abidemi. (2017). The Consumption-Oriented Capital Asset Price Model in the Nigerian Stock Exchange. Journal of Applied Statistics, 8(2):117-140.
Badiei, Milad, Ebrahimi Sarve Oliya, Mohammad Hassan, & Sargolzaei, Mostafa. (2024). Investigating the effect of investor sentiment on the efficiency of asset pricing factor models. The Journal of Economic Policy, 15(30):67-94, doi: 10.22034/EPJ.2024.20221.2444.(In Persian)
Basak, S., & H., Yan. (2010). Equilibrium asset prices and investor behavior in the presence of money illusion: A preference-based formulation. The Review of Economic Studies, 77(3): 914-936,  http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.623561..
Breeden, D. T., M. R. Gibbons, & R. H. Litzenberger. (1989). Empirical test of the consumption-oriented CAPM. Journal of Finance, 44(2): 231–262, https://doi.org/10.2307/2328589.
Breeden, D.T. (1979). An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and investment opportunities. Journal of Financial Economics, 7(3): 265–296, https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(79)90016-3.
Campbel, l Y. John, Giglio, Stefan, Polk, Christopher. (2018). An intertemporal CAPM with stochastic volatility. Journal of Financial Economics, 128(2): 207-233, DOI: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.02.011.
Chen, Z., & A. Lu. (2017). Seeing the unobservable from the invisible: The role of CO2 in measuring consumption risk. The Review of Finance, 12(3): 1-47, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2130823.
Elkamhi, Redouane, & Jo, Chanik. (2023). Asset holders’ consumption risk and tests of conditional CCAPM. Journal of Financial Economics, 148(3): 220-224, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2023.04.002.
Epstein, L.G., & S.E. Zin. (1991). Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: An empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 99(2): 263–286, https://doi.org/10.2307/1913778.
Gomes, J., L. Kogan, & M. Yogo. (2009). Durability of output and expected stock returns. Journal of Political Economy, 117(5): 941–986, https://doi.org/10.1086/648882.
Izadkhasti, Hojjat. (2018). Analyzing the Impact of Monetary Policy in a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model: Money in Utility Function Approach. Journal of Economic Modeling Research, 8(31):71-101. (In Persian)
Jacobs, K., & K.Q. Wang. (2004). Idiosyncratic consumption risk and the cross section of asset returns. Journal of Finance, 59(5): 2211–2252, DOI:10.2139/ssrn.302172.
Jagannathan, R., & Y. Wang. (2007). Lazy investors, discretionary consumption, and the cross-section of stock returns. Journal of Finance 62(4): 1623–1661, DOI:10.2139/ssrn.641682.
Kocherlakota, N., & L. Pistaferri. (2009). Asset pricing implications of Pareto optimality with private information. Journal of Political Economy, 117(3): 555–590,DOI: 10.1086/599761.
Top of Form
Kroencke, T.A. (2017). Asset pricing without garbage. Journal of Finance, 72(1):47–98, https://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12438.
Lettau, M., & S.C. Ludvigso. (2001). Resurrecting the (C) CAPM: A cross sectional test when risk premia are time-varying. Journal of Political Economy, 109(6): 1238–1287,  http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.935320
Lioui, A., & P. Maio. (2014). Interest rate risk and the cross-section of stock return. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 49(2): 83-511, DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1571481.
Lucas, R.E. (1978). Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica, 46(6): 1429–1445, https://doi.org/10.2307/1913837.
Lustig, H., & S. Van, Nieuwerburgh. (2005). Housing collateral, consumption insurance, and risk premia: An empirical perspective. Journal of Finance, 60(3): 1167–1219, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00759.x.
Maio Paulo. (2018). Does inflation explain equity risk premia? Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3097493.
Nadiri, Mohammad, & teymoor, Nohammadi. (2011). Estimating an Institutional Structure in Economic Growth Using GMM Dynamic Panel Data Method. Quarterly Journal of Economic Modelling, 5(15): 1-137. (In Persian).
Parker, J., & C. Julliard. (2005). Consumption risk and the cross section of expected returns. Journal of Political Economy, 113(1): 185–222, https://doi.org/10.1086/426042.
Savov, A. (2011). Asset pricing with garbage. Journal of Finance, 66(1): 177–201, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01629.x.
Weil, P. (1989). The equity premium puzzle and the risk-free rate puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 24(3): 401–421, https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(89)90028-7.
Yogo, M. (2006). A consumption-based explanation of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance, 61(2): 539–580, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00848.x.