تعیین سناریوی بهینه کاهش اثرات ناشی از شوک حذف ارز ترجیحی بر گروه‌های عمده غذایی؛ رهیافت مدل تعادل عمومی قابل محاسبه پویای بازگشتی (RDCGE)

نوع مقاله : مقاله پژوهشی

نویسنده

استادیار اقتصاد کشاورزی، مؤسسه پژوهش‌های برنامه‌ریزی، اقتصاد کشاورزی و توسعه روستایی، تهران، ایران.

چکیده

شواهد بیانگر آن است که سیاست حذف ارز ترجیحی از کالاهای اساسی، اگرچه منجر به کاهش میانگین تورم ماهانه گروه‌های عمده غذایی نسبت به دوره تخصیص ارز ترجیحی به کالاهای اساسی شده، لیکن، میانگین تورم نقطه‌به‌نقطه گروه‌های غذایی را افزایش داده است. حال، سؤال اساسی این است که در چه‌صورت اجرای سیاست مذکور، منجر به کاهش اثرات منفی بر تولید و مصرف گروه‌های عمده غذایی خواهد شد؟ براین اساس، در پژوهش حاضر نتایج حاصل از شبیه‌سازی 18 سناریو، در قالب نوع حذف ارز ترجیحی (یکباره، طی سه و طی پنج سال)، نوع جبران حمایتی (نقدی یا کالایی) و سطح پوشش حمایتی (تمامی دهک‌ها، دهک‌های پائین و متوسط یا تنها دهک‌های پائین درآمدی)، بر تولید و مصرف گروه‌های عمده غذایی (گوشت مرغ، تخم‌مرغ، شیر، گوشت قرمز و روغن خوراکی) بررسی شد. برای این منظور، داده‌های مورد نیاز از ماتریس حسابداری اجتماعی مرکز پژوهش‌های مجلس و جدول داده-ستانده بانک مرکزی گردآوری شد. جهت تجزیه‌وتحلیل داده‌ها نیز از مدل تعادل عمومی محاسبه‌پذیر پویای بازگشتی (RDCGE) و نرم‌افزار متلب استفاده شد. نتایج نشان داد در میان سناریوهای مورد بررسی، بهترین سناریو، سناریوی حذف ارز ترجیحی طی دوره پنج ساله، جبران حمایتی نقدی و پوشش حمایتی از دهک‌های پائین و متوسط درآمدی می‌باشد. بدین مفهوم که اگر دولت حذف ارز ترجیحی را به‌تدریج طی دوره پنج ساله انجام داده و بصورت نقدی از دهک‌های پائین و متوسط درآمدی حمایت کند، اثرات منفی ناشی از شوک آن بر تولید و مصرف گروه‌های عمده غذایی خنثی شده و سپس مثبت می‌شود.

کلیدواژه‌ها

موضوعات


عنوان مقاله [English]

Determining the Optimum Scenario to Reduce the Effects of Preferred Currency Removing Shocks on Major Food Groups; Recursive Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium (RDCGE) Approach

نویسنده [English]

  • Seyed Mohammad Fahimifard
Assistance Professor of Agricultural Economics, Agricultural Planning, Economic and Rural Development Research Institute (APERDRI), Tehran, Iran.
چکیده [English]

Purpose: The currency jump in early 2018 and the increase in prices during the following years caused the Iranian government to adopt a policy of preferential currency allocation (42000 Rials per US$) for the import of basic goods from August 2018. The main goal of this policy was to control the fluctuations of the domestic market and the decrease in the welfare of the society. However, the available evidence showed that, after a few years of the implementing this policy, due to the increase in the price of most targeted basic goods and the lack of profit of the lower-income deciles in an optimal way and the emergence of problems such as spread of rent and corruption and the diversion of allocated resources in the form of official re-export of inputs or final goods or smuggling, hoarding, overselling to the final consumer, etc., the policy of assigning preferential currency to essential goods was declared to be unsuccessful. Following the ineffectiveness of this policy, the Iranian government implemented the policy of removing preferential currency from basic goods in May 2022. The evidence shows that, although this policy has increased the price of major food groups (chicken meat, eggs, milk, red meat and edible oil), it has led to a continuous decrease in inflation of major food groups. However, the basic question is that ‘if the policy was implemented gradually, wouldn't it have better results?’ Also, ‘what type of support compensation for households (cash or goods) and what level of support coverage for income deciles would lead to better results?’ Therefore, the present study was conducted with the aim of determining the optimal scenario to reduce the effects of the shock of removing the preferential currency on the major food groups.
Methodology: In order to determine the optimal scenario of reducing the effects of the shock of removing the preferred currency on major food groups (chicken meat, eggs, milk, red meat and edible oil) 18 scenarios designed in the form of the type of removal of preferred currency from basic goods (at once, during 3-years and during 5-years period), the type of support compensation (cash or goods) and the level of coverage of income deciles (all income deciles, low and middle income deciles and only low income deciles) were discussed. For this purpose, the required data were collected from the social accounting matrix of the Islamic Parliament Research Center, Central Bank's input-output table, and Iran's Statistics Center. In addition, in order to analyze the data, the recursive dynamic calculable general equilibrium (RDCGE) model (which is based on the assumption of adaptive expectations) and Matlab software were used.
Discussion and Results: According to the results, the best scenario for reduct the negative effects of preferred currency removing shocks on major food groups is the scenario of removing the preferred currency from basic goods during a 5-years period, providing support in cash and providing support to the low and middle deciles of income, which has a positive effect on production, consumption, income of the factors of production (labor and capital), welfare of consumers, welfare of producers, and total welfare. In the sense that if the government gradually removes the preferential currency for basic goods over a 5 years period and supports the low- and middle-income deciles in cash, the negative effects caused by the shock of implementing preferred currency from basic goods in the society is neutralized and then becomes positive.
Conclusions and policy implications: Based on the results of the research, the best scenario is the elimination of the preferential currency during a 5-years period, cash compensation and the level of covering the low and middle-income deciles), it is suggested for the government officials to make the policy of removing the preferential currency from basic goods as close as possible to the proposed scenario and to support the consumers of basic goods in cash. This is because, in the method of compensation in the form of goods, some of the resources planned for the project can be ensured to be spent on buying basic goods and provide the minimum calories needed by the household, but the method leads to increased demand for basic goods, disruption of relative prices, and creation of a black market for commodity coupons. On the other hand, if the electronic coupons can only be cashed in certain distribution centers, it will create a kind of rent for selected distribution centers compared to micro distribution centers. In the cash method, however, the right of choice of the households is recognized from the beginning; since households can receive the subsidy payment in cash or purchase basic goods, it leads to the freedom of choice for them. As a result, the purchasing power of consumers' increases, which will subsequently lead to an increase in the production of goods including food. In addition, some believe that the cash support compensation will lead to an increase in inflation. If its resources are precisely determined and secured and the Central Bank's resources are not used for this purpose, it will not cause inflation. Also, the cash support compensation should not be such that in creates the impression of being permanent or long-term. Rather, it should be stated from the beginning that this subsidy is only to pass the transition and it temporarily supports the households.

کلیدواژه‌ها [English]

  • Removing of preferred currency
  • major food groups
  • income deciles
  • recursive dynamic computable general equilibrium (RDCGE) model
Aemi Bandeh Gharaei, H., Khodadad Kashi, F., & Mousavi Jahroomi, Y. (2019). Evaluating the Impact of Cash-subsidy on Poverty in Iran. Quarterly Journal of Economic Research and Policies, 27(89): 7-27. (In Persian)
Ahmadi, H., & Behboudi, M. R. (2023). Identifying the Adverse Impacts of Implementing the Targeted Subsidies Policy in Iran: Metasynthesis Approach. Iranian Journal of Economic Research, 28(94): 225-280. (In Persian)
Alexander, S. S. (1952). Effects of A Devaluation on A Trade Balance. Staff Papers - International Monetary Fund, 2(2): 263 -278.
Blakely, T., Cleghorn, C., Mizdrak, A., Waterlander, W., Nghiem, N., Swinburn, B., Wilson, N., & Ni Mhurchu, C. (2020). The Effect of Food Taxes and Subsidies on Population Health and Health Costs: A Modelling Study, Lancet Public Health, 5(7): e404-e413.
Blinder, A. S., & Deaton, A. (1985). The Time Series Consumption Function Revisited. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 465-521.
Boys, K. A., & Florax, R.J.G.M. (2007). Meta-Regression Estimates for CGE Models: A Case Study for Input Substitution Elasticities in Production Agriculture. American Agricultural Economics Association (New Name 2008: Agricultural and Applied Economics Association).
Breisingel, C., Engelke, W., & Ecker, O. (2012). Leveraging Fuel Subsidy Reform for Transition in Yemen, Sustainability, USA, 4, 2862-2887, 2862-2887.
Burfisher, M. E. (2017). Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models, 2nd edition, Cambridge University Press.
Decaluwé, B., Lemelin, A., Maisonnave, H., & Robichaud, V. (2013). «Pep-1-t», Standard PEP Model: Single-Country, Recursive Dynamic Version, Politique Économique et Pauvreté/Poverty and Economic Policy Network. Université Laval, Québec.
Fahimifard, S. M., Rafaati, M., & Gilanpour, O. (2022). Investigating the Effects of Removing the Preferred Exchange Rate of Agricultural Inputs on Agriculture Sector of Iran: RDCGE Approach. Agricultural Economics and Development, 30(2): 201-235. (In Persian)
Galloway, T. (2017). Canada’s Northern Food Subsidy Nutrition North Canada: A Comprehensive Program Evaluation. International Journal of Circumpolar Health, 76(1): 1279451.
Hosoe, N., Gasawa, K., & Hashimoto, H. (2010). Textbook of Computable General Equilibrium Modeling, Programming and Simulations, Palgrave Macmillan UK.
Hosseini, S. S., Pakravan Charvadeh, M. R., & Salami, H. (2016). The Effect of Subsidy Reform Program on Food Security in Iran. Iranian Journal of Economic Research, 21(67): 53-82. (In Persian)
Hummel, A., & Ziesemer, V. (2021). Food Subsidies in General Equilibrium, Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 2021-069/VI, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3890104 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3890104.
Iyke, B. N., & Ho, S. Y. (2020). Consumption and Exchange Rate Uncertainty: Evidence from Selected Asian Countries. The World Economy, 43(9): 2437 -62.
Jha, R., Gaiha, R., Pandey, M. K., & Kaicker, N. (2013). Food Subsidy, Income Transfer and the Poor: A Comparative Analysis of the Public Distribution System in India's States. Journal of Policy Modeling, 35(6): 887-908.
Kazemi, S. A., & Jalili Bolhassani, H. (2022). Investigating the Volume of Subsidies in Iran; Its Economic and Security Dimensions. Defense Economics, 6(22): 133-153. (In Persian)
Khorami Moghadam, S., Zare Mehrgerdi, M. R., Mehrabi Boshrabadi, H., & Bakhshoodeh, M. (2014). An Analysis of the Effect Reducing the Food Subsidy on Income Inequality. Agricultural Economics, 8(1): 119-136. (In Persian)
Löfgren, H., Harris, R. L., & Robinson, S. (2001). A Standard Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Model in GAMS. TMD Discussion Papers 75, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
Nejabat, E., Amirkhani, A., Mooghali, A., & Darvish, H. (2022). Identifying and Explaining the Characteristics of "Good Subsidy". Social Welfare Quarterly, 21(83): 167-228. (In Persian)
Niebylski, M. L., Redburn, K. A., Duhaney, T., & Campbell, N. (2015). Healthy Food Subsidies and Unhealthy Food Taxation: A Systematic Eeview of the Evidence. Nutrition, 31(6): 787-795.
Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (1998). Risk and Exchange Rates. NBER Working Papers No. w6694, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Omar, D. A. (2021). Food Subsidy Reform: Case of Egypt, Thesis, The American University in Cairo, AUC Knowledge Fountain.
Organizations Making Targeted Subsidies (2022). Available at: https://www.hadafmandi.ir. (In Persian)
Ramadan, R., & Thomas, A. (2011). Evaluating the Impact of Reforming the Food Subsidy Program in Egypt: A Mixed Demand Approach. Food Policy, 36: 638-646.
Roustaei Tale Jerdi, S. (2023). Examining the Plan to Reform the Bread Subsidy Payment System By the Iranian Government in 2022, Working Paper of Iran Islamic Paliament Research Center, No. 18606. (In Persian)
Sayadi, M., Shakeri, A., Mohammadi, T., & Bahrami, J. (2016). Stochastic Shocks and Oil Revenue Management in Iran; A Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Approach. Economics Research, 16(61): 33-80. (In Persian)
Shabanzadeh Khoshrody, M., Gilanpour, O., Javdan, E., & Rafaati, M. (2022). The Effect of Preferred Currency Subsidies Policy on Food Consumption in Urban Areas of Iran. Economic Research, 22(3): 129-155. (In Persian)
Soflaie Shahrbabak, E., Mosavi, S. H., & Mortazavi, S. A. (2018). The Effects of Bread Subsidy Elimination on Changes in Import Dependency Ratio and Food Security. Agricultural Economics Research, 10(39): 55-82. (In Persian)
Soltani, A., & Heydari Monavar, A. (2020). Economic and Social Effects of Targeted Subsidies Scheme on Household Welfare Level (Tabriz City Case Study). Journal of Economic & Developmental Sociology, 9(2): 175-205. (In Persian)
Statistical Center of Iran (2023). Available at: https://www.amar.org.ir/.(In Persian)
Wachtel, P. (1972). Interrelated Models of Household Behavior: A Summary and an Extension. Journal of Finance, American Finance Association, 27(2): 503-506.
Wing, I. S., & Balistreri, E. J. (2018). Computable General Equilibrium Models for Policy Evaluation and Economic Consequence Analysis, Oxford University Press.
Zhao, Y. (2020). The Influence and Impact of the Exchange Rate on the Economy. In E3S Web of Conferences (Vol. 214, p. 03007). EDP Sciences